Introduction

The theory of critical mass argues that apparently stable social conventions can be overturned by a minority of committed individuals if such minority reaches a critical size1,2,3. In this view, the power of small factions comes not from their authority or wealth but from the commitment to the cause and also, crucially, from their size. Evidence from different contexts however shows a wide range of possible sizes. On the one hand, several studies have found that rather large minority sizes were required to overturn a majority. Qualitative analyses of gender conventions in corporate leadership roles have hypothesised that a critical mass of 30% of the population is necessary in order for the tipping point to be reached4,5. Related observational work has proposed a higher critical mass size approaching 40% of the population6. Controlled experiments of social coordination have brought empirical evidence for tipping points in the dynamics of social conventions, finding a critical threshold of 25% of the population7. On the other hand, numerous observations suggest that even a minority counting just tens of committed individuals, and not significant fractions of the population, may trigger abrupt social and normative change. Social movements8 offer several examples in this sense (see9,10,11 and examples therein), and a data-driven analysis of linguistic norm change in English and Spanish pointed out that committed minorities as small as 0.3% of the population can impose their view12.

To understand the origin and nature of critical masses, several frameworks have been proposed to investigate their role in human behaviour, the dynamics of opinions, and the emergence of norms and consensus, starting from simple models inspired by statistical physics13,14,15,16,17. In particular, the naming game (NG) model has been influential in the theoretical description of the emergence of social norms18,19,20. The model describes how a shared convention can emerge in a population of agents that interact locally with their peers, without any central coordination. It has brought theoretical support to the tipping points hypothesis, as a critical mass of 10% was shown to be able to induce norm change in this model3. Subsequent generalisations of this model yielded critical mass varying between 10% and 40% of the population depending on the strength of individual commitment21. Adding further ingredients to the model, it was even possible to obtain vanishing sizes for the critical masses22,23,24,25,26. However, despite the wide range of observed critical mass sizes and of potential theoretical descriptions, little attention has been devoted to the problem of explaining how the initial group building up the critical mass itself emerges, and what are its structural and dynamical determinants. Qualitative hypothesis include the existence of an intermediate phase composed by an initially small core of committed individuals able to recruit the missing mass of peers necessary to trigger a behavioural cascade27. To this aim, small groups could exploit the role of high-resource individuals to mobilise the masses28, homophily and local coalition formation27, or the role of non-committed individuals sitting at the periphery of the social network (‘slacktivists’)29. In all cases, the effect of small groups—and group interactions—can be determinant. Indeed, group interactions are the building blocks of real-world social systems, from discussions in real life between a group of friends to collaboration networks, and including online discussions on online social media and forums, which can involve large numbers of individuals30,31,32,33,34. Recent works in complex systems research have focused on taking into account these more realistic higher-order (non-pairwise) interactions35,36,37,38,39,40,41. This includes models of opinion dynamics such as the majority rule42,43, or extensions of other models describing social and evolutionary dynamics to hypergraphs44,45,46,47,48, leading to important changes of dynamical behaviour. For instance, group interactions can dramatically alter social contagion dynamics and lead to a rich phenomenology including abrupt transitions, bi-stability and critical mass phenomena49.

Here, we investigate the role of group interactions on critical mass effects. To this aim, we extend the widely adopted naming game framework, which has been shown to explain the outcome of controlled experiments7, to account for more realistic interaction patterns and dynamics. We improve the modelling along three directions. First, we propose a model to describe norm evolution upon group interactions between any number of agents. We thus encode these many-body interactions into the hyperlinks of a hypergraph50, which provides a more faithful representation of real-world social structures36,40, and define new rules for group agreement. Second, we take into account that social influence is in general not perfect51,52,53. Thus, individuals may successfully interact with one another without necessarily converging on a norm adoption as a result of the interaction. More specifically, while in the standard naming game model a successful coordination is followed by a certain and exclusive adoption of the norm that allowed the coordination16,18 (perfect social influence54), here individuals may be reluctant to let go of alternative conventions even when they successfully manage to coordinate with one another on a specific norm. Third, we inform the model with a variety of real-world data concerning the structure of empirical social networks and their microscopic (non-pairwise) interactions. This represents an improvement with respect to standard all-to-all, pairwise, or synthetic approaches. Taken together, these three advances contribute towards a more realistic representation of both social interactions and dynamics. Extensive numerical simulations of this model on empirical data and synthetic hypergraphs show that the critical mass required to induce norm change is dramatically reduced when non-committed members of the population are not fully susceptible to social influence. We also find a rich phenomenology in which groups modulate the takeover by helping sustaining the view of the minority. In particular, we unveil a non-monotonic dependency in the long term dynamical output: interactions in very small or very large size turn out to be more favourable to the committed minority than interactions in groups of intermediate size. Our results hold when considering data from very different social contexts and in a simplified version of the interaction structure, for which we develop an analytical mean-field approach, allowing us to get further insights and study the interplay between social influence and size of the committed minority.

Results

The Framework

In order to include a more realistic description of social interactions, we generalise the standard NG by considering that agents can interact not only in pairs but also in groups of arbitrary size. Groups are indeed the most natural units through which individuals engage with each other in social contexts30,31,32,34, and it has been shown that considering these higher-order interactions may reveal a rich phenomenology36,41. While the usual NG considers that the agents are located on the nodes of a network and interact along its links, we therefore encode here the group interactions between the agents as the hyperlinks of a hypergraph. This higher-order representation of the social structure, in which pairwise interactions (links) [i, j] are called 1-interactions, expands the more traditional representation offered by graphs by considering relationships between any number of agents, such as 2-interactions (triangles) [i, j, k], 3-interactions (tetrahedra), etc: a hyperlink is simply a set of nodes [p0, p1, …, pk−1] that conveniently represents a multi-body interaction between k nodes36,50.

The evolution rules of the game in the generalised setting are the following. At each time step a hyperlink e is randomly chosen and a speaker agent is chosen at random among the nodes composing e. All the other nodes participating in the same hyperlink act as hearers. The speaker selects a random name, say A, from its current vocabulary and communicates it to the group. In the pairwise NG interactions, there is only one hearer and the agreement can be reached if and only if the hearer has the name A in its vocabulary. Here, the introduction of group interactions requires the definition of a new generalised condition on the group of hearers for an agreement to be possible. Multiple options are obviously possible. The strictest possible condition is that the agreement can be reached by the group only if all the hearers have A in their vocabularies. This agreement rule can be seen as a unanimity condition rule between the hearers’ vocabularies. On the other hand, the weakest condition would be that an agreement can be reached provided at least one of the hearers knows the name already. We call this the union rule, as it is enough that the name is in the union of the vocabularies of the hearers. The unanimity condition seems more suitable when modelling consensus, as it implies that all members of the interacting group need to know a name to converge to it. On the other hand, in the union rule, an alliance of two agents (the speaker and one hearer) can make a group of arbitrary size converge. We thus focus mainly on the unanimity condition rule in the main text. We show the results for the union rule in the Supplementary Note 2, and mention where relevant how the results differ between the two rules. Intermediate rules such that a given fraction or number of hearers need to have the name in their vocabularies could also be considered.

In all cases, the propensity of the hearers to accept the convergence to a consensus in the group is controlled by a parameter β [0, 1] (notice that this parameter contributes only when an agreement is possible)20. Thus, if an agreement can be reached, two possibilities exist [Fig. 1a]: (i) with probability β all the nodes of the considered hyperlink agree on the chosen name A and erase all the other names from their vocabularies [Fig. 1b]; (ii) with probability 1 − β there is no convergence but the nodes who did not have A add it to their vocabulary. When agreement is instead not possible, all nodes who did not have A add it to their vocabulary [Fig. 1c, d]. Thus, the parameter β modulates social influence, i.e. the propensity of individuals to change their behaviour to meet the demands of a social environment. The smaller the β the less the individuals participating are prone to change their views in spite of the social influence mechanism55,56,57.

Fig. 1: Dynamics of the model.
figure 1

Agents are represented by the nodes of a social structure composed by interacting groups of different sizes. The vocabulary of the agents--for simplicity containing at most only two names (or conventions) {A, B}--is reflected in the colours of the nodes as shown in the legend. At each interaction, a group is chosen at random (highlighted in yellow in the figure) together with a speaker (node 1), while the remaining nodes act as hearers. Here we illustrate the unanimity rule (see model definition). a The speaker chooses a name at random from its vocabulary (here, A), and communicates it to the rest of the group. Since A is present in the vocabularies of all the hearers (nodes 2 and 3 support A, while node 4 knows both names), the group can reach an agreement. b With probability β the group agrees on the chosen name, and all nodes involved immediately update their vocabulary to A, erasing B. With probability 1 − β instead the agreement does not happen. c In this case, the speaker selects A, but node 3 does not possess A in its vocabulary. d Thus, there cannot be agreement in the group. Nevertheless, all hearers update their vocabularies by adding the heard name, i.e., node 3 switches from A to A,B.

Finally, we allow for the presence of a committed minority among the agents. The dynamics of these committed agents does not obey the aforementioned rules. Instead, this fraction p of agents always sticks to the same name and does not change it nor updates their vocabulary3. For simplicity of notations and consistency throughout the manuscript, we assign to these agents the name A (and we denote their fraction as Ac). We will also denote with nx(t) the fraction of agents supporting name x at a given time t, and with \({n}_{x}^{* }\) the corresponding values in the stationary states reached in the long time regime.

Critical mass dynamics

We first show how the model allows for minority takeover even in extreme cases. In Fig. 2a-c we show an example of how a small minority, consisting here of a single committed individual (0.3% of the population of 327 individuals), can overturn the majority. The example reports the results of a single simulation (representative of 95% of the runs we have simulated) of a NG with the unanimity rule and β = 0.336. The considered empirical social structure consists of face-to-face interactions—as recorded by wearable sensors in a French high-school58—and includes group interactions of sizes ranging from 2 to 5 (see Methods for details). The committed individual is selected at random. We show in Fig. 2a visualisations of the structure of interactions (showing for simplicity only the links and not the groups of larger sizes) and of the states of the nodes at several times during the simulation. Figure 2b moreover shows the temporal evolution of the fraction of nodes supporting a given name x (solid lines) until the absorbing state with all nodes converging on A is reached. The circular markers on the curves correspond to the times at which the five configurations of Fig. 2a were observed. In these visualisations, we distinguish the committed agent by a lighter orange cross (Ac). Notice that this is the only node initially supporting A (nA(0) = 0), while the remaining nodes are initially assigned the name B (nB(0) = 1 − p), represented by a blue colour. As time evolves, the committed agent starts to spread name A locally: The fraction of nodes supporting both names at the same time (but without preference for either one, and represented by white nodes) increases around the committed one, who converts a number of blue neighbours into white nodes, that subsequently start to further diffuse the name A. At later times, we observe a change in the slope of nA(t): the fraction of nodes having adopted A starts to rapidly increase up to the point when nA,B(t) reaches a maximum and starts decreasing, while the initial minority takes over.

Fig. 2: Critical mass dynamics.
figure 2

a Illustrative example of a simulation of the Naming Game (NG) with unanimity rule on an empirical social structure (Thiers13), where a minority Ac of one single committed individual supporting A--consisting of 0.3% of the population of 327 individuals--overturns the stable social norms and reaches global consensus (under imperfect communication, with social influence parameter β = 0.336). b Temporal evolution of the fraction nx(t) of nodes supporting name x. Different solid lines correspond to different names, x = {A + Ac, B, (A, B)}. Dashed lines are reported as a benchmark, representing the case with perfect communication (β = 1). c Temporal evolution of the normalised size of the largest connected component (LCC) of nodes supporting name A (red curve) and nodes that have A (but not necessarily A only) in their vocabulary (green curve). Panels d, e, f, g show the temporal evolution of the dynamics with committed minorities (p = 3%) on empirical higher-order structures. The social structures are constructed from empirical data sets collected in six different context: a workplace (InVS15)84, a primary school (LyonSchool)85, a conference (SFHH)86, a high school (Thiers13)58, email communications (Email-EU)87 and a political congress (Congress-bills)88. The temporal evolution of the densities of nodes holding name A and holding both A and B are reported in panels (d, e) and (f, g), respectively, for two different values of the parameter β quantifying the efficacy of reaching an agreement within a group, namely β = 0.28 (d, f) and β = 0.41 (e, g). The results over different runs of stochastic simulations are reported as median values (solid lines) and values contained within the 25th and 75th percentiles (shaded areas).

Figure 2b shows also, as a benchmark, the outcome of a simulation with the same committed individual but β = 1. The associated temporal evolution, where the minority remains as such (dashed lines), confirms the central role played, in the minority takeover, by the parameter β that encodes the propensity of individuals to accept the convergence to a consensus in a group. Finally, Fig. 2c shows the temporal evolution of the normalised sizes of the largest connected component (LCC) of nodes supporting name A (or Ac) and of the LCC of nodes that know A, namely with vocabulary either A, Ac or A, B. More precisely, we consider the subgraph induced by the nodes having the considered status, we compute the size of its LCC and then normalise it by the total number of nodes. As the simulation evolves the subgraphs start growing around the committed node until they span the entire population, the subgraph of nodes knowing A naturally growing faster than the subgraph of nodes whose inventory contains only A.

Analysis of different regimes

To clarify the role of the underlying social structure and of the corresponding group interactions, we study the evolution of the model on different empirical data sets of interactions. To this aim, we rely on publicly available data sets of different kinds of temporally-resolved social interactions, from which we can construct aggregated higher-order (group) representations (see also49). The data we use were collected in six different contexts, namely a workplace (InVS15), a primary school (LyonSchool), a conference (SFHH), a high school (Thiers13, the data set used in Fig. 2), email communications (Email-EU) and a political congress (Congress-bills). The resulting hypergraphs are very different in terms of group size distribution, with some containing groups up to size 24. We provide additional information on the data and the data aggregation methodology in ‘Methods’.

We first simulate the model on each structure, with p = 3% (see Methods for details of the numerical simulations) and different values of β. Figure 2d–g shows the results averaged across 50 different runs for each empirical structure. In each panel, the fraction of nodes supporting name x is plotted as a function of time [panels (d,e) x = A + Ac, panels (f,g) x = (A, B)] for two different values of β, namely β = 0.28 (d,f) and β = 0.41 (e,g) [see also Supplementary Fig. 1]. Clearly, and despite the significant differences among the data sets, the dynamics falls into the same two radically different regimes depending on the parameter β. For low values of β [β = 0.28, Fig. 2d, f], all the curves stabilise after some time—that depends on the considered structure—on similar and intermediate values of the densities of individuals with norm A or B. In this scenario the initial very small minority of committed individuals manages to strongly expand the reach of the name A, but does not convince the entire population. Instead, there is a co-existence regime, where the number of agents supporting name A remains globally fairly constant, while, microscopically, the nodes continue to switch between different states. We note that this regime is not present in the traditional NG (β = 1) where a global consensus is always reached at long times. The picture changes for larger values of β [β = 0.41, Fig. 2e, g]. After an initial transient, there is an abrupt transition (with a temporal scale that depends on the particular structure) after which the minority manages to convince the entire population and simulations reach the absorbing state of global coherence (with name A). Notice how the nAB(t) curve typically presents a peak right before \({n}_{A+{A}_{c}}(t)\) starts to increase, corresponding to the behaviour already highlighted in the single run investigated in Fig. 2b: the information about name A diffuses from the committed, making the vocabulary of individuals who have B first become (A, B) and finally switch to A. We also illustrate this behaviour in Supplementary Fig. 2, by showing that the average time for individuals to adopt A (exclusively) for the first time increases with their distance from a committed individual.

We further characterise the behaviour of the model by studying how the stationary state changes with β. Simulation results are shown in Fig. 3, where we plot the fraction of nodes holding each name (A or B) in the stationary state as a function of β, either without committed individuals (p = 0) or with a fraction p = 0.03 of committed (see Supplementary Figures 3, 4 for the results for the other data sets, as well as for different values of the fraction of committed p and for the union condition rule for group agreement). Figure 3a, b highlights the rich behaviour of the model as β changes from 0 to 1, with several clearly distinct regimes. In the absence of committed minorities [p = 0, Fig. 3a], we initialise the simulations with 40% of individuals supporting name A (nB(0) = 0.6), and we obtain two distinct regimes. For low values of β, the system reaches a stationary state where the two names co-exist and have on average the same density: neither one dominates, and a substantial fraction of individuals hold the two names in their vocabulary (as even when there is no local convergence because β is small, the hearers add the speaker’s norm to their vocabulary, which favours the emergence of agents having both names). However, as consensus becomes easier (increasing β), the social influence within groups tends to favour the name of the initial majority (B). Above a critical value βc that varies with the structure, the dynamics falls into the absorbing state with no A agents left. In contrast with the pairwise NG model in20, the transition is not abrupt. There is in fact a third intermediate regime–whose extent strongly depends on the social structure–where names co-exist, but B dominates.

Fig. 3: Stationary state of the naming game (NG) dynamics with unanimity rule simulated on empirical higher-order structures, and histograms of the group sizes of these structures.
figure 3

The considered social structures correspond to empirical data sets collected in four different contexts (see Methods): a conference (SFHH), a high school (Thiers13), email communications (Email-EU) and a political congress (Congress-bills). Panels a and b correspond respectively to simulations without and with committed minorities Ac supporting name A (respectively, fraction of committed p = 0 and p = 3%). In these panels, we plot the fraction of nodes supporting name x in the stationary state, \({n}_{x}^{* }(\beta )\), obtained by means of numerical simulations on each data set, as a function of the social influence parameter β. Lines (continuous and dashed, respectively associated to names A + Ac and B) and shaded areas refer to the median values and values contained within the 25th and 75th percentile measured over 150 runs. The panels c shows the histograms of group sizes associated to each data set, where a group of size k represents a higher-order interaction (of order k − 1) between k nodes.

A radically different scenario emerges when a committed minority is present. The system exhibits three different regimes, illustrated in Figure 3b that gives the results of simulations performed with a small seed of committed agents (chosen at random) with name A, all other agents having initially the name B (p = 0.03, nA(0) = 0, nB(0) = 1 − p). At small values of β, as for the former case, local convergence within each group interaction is hard, and a stationary state with co-existence of the two names is reached. Name A, despite being known initially only to a small minority, reaches nevertheless a substantial fraction of the population and is actually more represented than B even in this regime. As β increases, the advantage gained by A becomes rapidly stronger until we reach an absorbing state in which the initial minority wins and conquers the entire population, while name B, which was initially shared by the majority (97%) of the population, disappears. This regime persists for a certain range of β values that we call Δβ*. At larger β finally, we enter a third regime where the committed minority is not able to spread its norm widely, and the system converges to a stationary state where the name supported by the initial majority prevails, with the obvious exception of the committed agents, and with a small fraction of agents in contact with the committed who tend to have a shared vocabulary (A, B).

This phenomenology is qualitatively robust, despite different underlying social interaction structures. Figure 3c shows the numbers of groups of each size contained in each data set. Face-to-face interactions involve relatively low number of agents, so that group sizes are limited; on the contrary, email communications (Email-EU) and political networks of bills co-sponsoring (Congress-bills) can correspond to larger groups, involving up to 24 individuals, with a heterogeneous distribution of group sizes. The social structure influences the quantitative results of the long term dynamics, as the larger intervals Δβ* are associated to the data sets that include large groups. We have verified that these quantitative differences are due indeed to group size distributions and not to particular correlations that might be present in the data, by performing simulations using a group-size-based mean-field approach, as in Supplementary Figure 5: in these simulations, the data are reshuffled so that the group size distribution is preserved but other correlations are destroyed. The differences in the width of the Δβ* interval in which the committed minority prevails are preserved, showing that the size of the groups plays an important role. We investigate this role more systematically in the next section.

The role of group size

The results discussed above show a similar phenomenology for different social contexts corresponding to different interaction patterns, with different group sizes and generalised degree distributions59 (see Supplementary Fig. 6). In this section, we explore more systematically the impact of group size on the outcome of the dynamics, and, in particular, its interplay with the existence of a committed minority. We therefore consider synthetic interaction structures where we control the distribution of group sizes. For simplicity, we consider homogeneous structures in which individuals interact in groups of fixed size (uniform hypergraphs). Figure 4 shows the results of stochastic simulations on such (k − 1)-uniform hypergraphs, where each hyperlink consists of exactly k nodes. In Fig. 4a–h we plot the median fraction of nodes supporting name x in the stationary state, \({n}_{x}^{* }(\beta )\), as a function of β for several group sizes. Panels (a,c,e,g) and (b,d,f,h) show the results of simulations initiated with a different fraction of committed nodes holding name A, set respectively to p = 0.01 and p = 0.03 (all the other nodes holding initially name B). When varying the group size from k = 2 (a,b) to k = 5 (c,d), the range Δβ* in which the committed convert the whole population to A decreases. However, when we further increase the group size (g,h), Δβ* increases again. Thus, increasing k changes the range of β values for which the minority manages to take over the entire population in a non-monotonic way. This range also depends on the committed population size p, with a broader range for larger p. Similar plots for different agreement rules can be found in Supplementary Fig. 7. Figure 4i further highlights this non-monotonic dependence of k by plotting the optimal range Δβ* as a function of k for different values of p, for the unanimity rule. We also show in Supplementary Fig. 8 the evolution with k of the minimal and maximal values of this range, \({\beta }_{min}^{* }\) and \({\beta }_{max}^{* }\), for both rules. For the intersection rule, both are non-monotonic with k: at small k, \({\beta }_{min}^{* }\) increases and \({\beta }_{max}^{* }\) decreases, while both reverse their tendency at larger k. On the other hand, for the union rule, \({\beta }_{max}^{* }\) increases monotonically with k and only \({\beta }_{min}^{* }\) keeps a non monotonic behaviour. This complex behaviour can be interpreted by several competing effects of the group size. Let us first consider large β. For the intersection rule, the unanimity condition makes it more difficult for an agreement to be possible on a minority name when the group size increases; on the other hand, more individuals are converted to the new name upon each single successful agreement. The competition between these effects leads to a non-monotonic \({\beta }_{max}^{* }\). For the union rule, the first effect does not exist, and increasing group size makes it more probable for a minority speaker to find a hearer knowing the minority name: \({\beta }_{max}^{* }\) increases monotonically with k. At small β and low k, co-existence of norms is favoured for both rules by increasing k (hence \({\beta }_{min}^{* }\) increases), because it is more probable that both norms are represented when a larger group is chosen to interact; as β is small, local consensus is not very probable and instead the most probable outcome is that all agents gain the word of the speaker in their inventories, thus becoming (A, B). As k continues to increase however, the local convergence of large groups starts to dominate and \({\beta }_{min}^{* }\) starts thus to decrease. We note that similar competing effects of group sizes have been described in a different type of cascade dynamics60, leading to non-monotonic group size effects. Moreover, this phenomenology provides quantitative support to the so-called group size paradox well-studied in sociology61. We also notice that even for large values of β (in the regime where the name supported by the committed minority does not reach the entire population) group interactions still play a major role in keeping the system out of the absorbing state of the majority and promoting the alternative norm. This is evident from Fig. 4j, where we report the fraction of agents having both names in the stationary state as a function of k, for a fixed value of β = 0.71, which—depending on k and p—might fall inside or outside of the optimal range Δβ*. The corresponding points are also highlighted in Fig. 4a–h. We see that \({n}_{AB}^{* }\) increases with the group size, up to the point where the minority wins. Notice how this fraction of individuals holding both norms becomes easily much larger than p, highlighting how the committed individuals propagate the knowledge of the alternative name to a substantial part of the population, even when they do not manage to completely reverse the initial majority.

Fig. 4: Higher-order (group) effects in the naming game (NG) for different values of the social influence parameter β.
figure 4

We consider (k − 1) − uniform hypergraphs, i.e. regular structures in which each interaction involves exactly k agents. Group agreement follows the unanimity rule. ah The density of nodes supporting name x in the stationary state, \({n}_{x}^{* }(\beta )\), obtained by means of numerical simulations, is shown as a function of the social influence parameter β (Ac: committed minority). Lines (continuous and dashed, respectively associated to names A + Ac and B) and shaded areas refer to the median values and values contained within the 25th and 75th percentiles of the 50 numerical simulations. a, c, e, g and b, d, f, h correspond to simulations with different sizes of committed minorities supporting name A, namely fractions p = 0.01 and p = 0.03 of the population. In the initial state, all the other agents hold norm B. Four different group sizes are considered: k = 2 (a, b), k = 5 (c, d), k = 10 (e, f) and k = 40 (g, h). The range Δβ* of β values for which \({n}_{A}^{* }=1\) (i.e., the committed minority manages to convert the whole population), is plotted in (i) as a function of the group size k and for different values of the fraction p of committed (see legend). We show in Supplementary Figure 8 the equivalent of this panel for the union rule. j Fraction of nodes \({n}_{AB}^{* }\) holding both names in the stationary state as a function of k for different values of p.

Analytical approach

To get further insights on the observed behaviour, its dependency on the parameters of the model, as well as to access the impact of the microscopic rule for group agreement, we finally consider a mean-field (MF) description of the generalised model. We limit here our study to groups of three nodes as the number of potential combinations becomes soon intractable as the group size increases. We thus consider an infinitely large homogeneously mixing population such that each interaction involves three nodes taken at random, obeying the rules of the NG defined above, under the unanimity condition rule for reaching an agreement. The equations for the dynamical evolution of the densities of agents having each possible vocabulary, nA, nB and nAB, can then be written as:

$${d}_{t}{n}_{A}= -2{n}_{A}^{2}{n}_{B}+\left(\frac{5}{2}\beta -1\right){n}_{A}^{2}{n}_{AB}\\ -2{n}_{A}{n}_{B}^{2}-3{n}_{A}{n}_{B}{n}_{AB}\\ +(4\beta -1){n}_{A}{n}_{AB}^{2}+\frac{3}{2}\beta {n}_{AB}^{3}+\frac{5}{2}\beta {p}^{2}{n}_{AB}\\ +p\left[-2{n}_{A}{n}_{B}+(5\beta -1){n}_{A}{n}_{AB}+4\beta {n}_{AB}^{2}\right]\\ {d}_{t}{n}_{B}= -2{n}_{B}^{2}{n}_{A}+\left(\frac{5}{2}\beta -1\right){n}_{B}^{2}{n}_{AB}\\ -2{n}_{B}{n}_{A}^{2}-3{n}_{B}{n}_{A}{n}_{AB}\\ +(4\beta -1){n}_{B}{n}_{AB}^{2}+\frac{3}{2}\beta {n}_{AB}^{3}-2{p}^{2}{n}_{B}\\ -p\left[4{n}_{A}{n}_{B}+2{n}_{B}^{2}+3{n}_{B}{n}_{AB}\right]\\ {n}_{AB}= 1-{n}_{A}-{n}_{B}-p$$
(1)

where dt denotes the time derivative.

Similar equations can be derived for different agreement rules, such as for the less strict union rule, in which having one of the hearers knowing the name expressed by the speaker is potentially enough to reach consensus in the entire group. The evolution equations in this case read

$${d}_{t}{n}_{A}= \,2(\beta -1){n}_{A}^{2}{n}_{B}+\left(\frac{5}{2}\beta -1\right){n}_{A}^{2}{n}_{AB}\\ -2{n}_{A}{n}_{B}^{2}+(6\beta -3){n}_{A}{n}_{B}{n}_{AB}\\ +(4\beta -1){n}_{A}{n}_{AB}^{2}+3\beta {n}_{B}{n}_{AB}^{2}+\frac{3}{2}\beta {n}_{AB}^{3}\\ +{p}^{2}\left[2\beta {n}_{B}+\frac{5}{2}\beta {n}_{AB}\right]+p\left[2(2\beta -1){n}_{A}{n}_{B}\right. \\ \left.+(5\beta -1){n}_{A}{n}_{AB}+6\beta {n}_{B}{n}_{AB}+4\beta {n}_{AB}^{2}\right] \\ {d}_{t}{n}_{B}= \, 2(\beta -1){n}_{B}^{2}{n}_{A}+\left(\frac{5}{2}\beta -1\right){n}_{B}^{2}{n}_{AB}\\ -2{n}_{B}{n}_{A}^{2}+(6\beta -3){n}_{B}{n}_{A}{n}_{AB}\\ +(4\beta -1){n}_{B}{n}_{AB}^{2}+3\beta {n}_{A}{n}_{AB}^{2}+\frac{3}{2}\beta {n}_{AB}^{3}\\ -2{p}^{2}{n}_{B}-p[2{n}_{B}^{2}+(3-3\beta ){n}_{B}{n}_{AB}]\\ -p[-2\beta {n}_{AB}^{2}+4{n}_{A}{n}_{B}]\\ {n}_{AB}= \, 1-{n}_{A}-{n}_{B}-p.$$
(2)

Equations for the benchmark pairwise rule, without higher-order interactions, are reported in Supplementary Note 1.

To explore the interplay between the size of the committed minority and the social influence parameter β in determining the final state of the system evolving according to these equations, we integrate them numerically. For both rules, we use the same initial condition as in the previous sections: we fix a fraction p > 0 of committed agents and a value for β, and we set nA(0) = nAB(0) = 0 so that initially the only agents with name A are the committed ones, all the others holding name B (nB(0) = 1 − p). We record the evolution of the densities nx(t) until they reach a stationary value (results are also confirmed by directly imposing the stationarity condition dt = 0, and solving the resulting equations through the programme Mathematica).

This allows us to study how the final fraction of agents holding name A, \({n}_{A+{A}_{c}}^{* }\equiv {n}_{A}(t\to \infty )+p\), depends on p and β. Results are shown in Fig. 5 as three-dimensional phase diagrams. We also show, to make the link with previous figures clearer, a curve (in black) of \({n}_{A+{A}_{c}}^{* }\) as a function of β for a fixed fraction of committed individuals (p = 0.08). With the unanimity condition [Fig. 5a] three regimes emerge, as observed before with stochastic simulations: at low β the committed manage to create a co-existence of names, with \({n}_{A+{A}_{c}}^{* } > > \;p\), but do not overturn the initial majority. In the central region, whose width depends on the size of the committed minority p (see also Supplementary Fig. 9), the new name A prevails and the initially general name B completely disappears. Finally, at large enough β the system is not much perturbed by the committed. Overall, the larger the committed minority, the higher β needs to be to avoid the initial name to disappear. This phenomenology persists for different agreement rules, as for the less restrictive union condition shown in Fig. 5b. In this case, for p = 0.08 the third regime vanishes and the optimal range Δβ* expands up to the case β = 1 corresponding to the perfect social influence scenario (as for the standard NG). We also note that the results of our MF approach are in perfect agreement with the ones from stochastic simulations, here reported as white circles (further comparisons with stochastic simulations are reported in Supplementary Figures 10, 11). Additional heatmaps for both rules and the pairwise benchmark are reported in Supplementary Figs. 12, 13.

Fig. 5: Mean field (MF) phase diagrams of the naming game with committed minorities on 2-uniform hypergraphs.
figure 5

Each three-dimensional surface (grey/yellow shading is only for visualisation purposes) gives the stationary fraction of agents supporting name A (z-axis) as a function of the social influence parameter β and of the fraction p of agents committed to A (Ac). Different panels correspond to different conditions for group agreement, namely unanimity (a) and “union" (b). The surfaces are obtained through numerical integration of Eq. (1) and Eq. (2) at fixed p, β, with initial conditions nA(0) = 0, nB(0) = 1 − p, nAB(0) = 0. Example curves with p = 0.08 are shown with solid black lines. The associated results of stochastic simulations (circles) for homogeneous systems of 1000 agents are shown for comparison.

Discussion

Online connectedness is reportedly speeding up the process of collective behavioural change62,63 through the adoption of new norms7,64,65,66. In this scenario, clarifying the microscopic mechanisms driving this process is key to gain a better understanding of our society and to design possible interventions aimed at contrasting undesired effects. At the same time, understanding how policy can create tipping points where none exist, and how it can push the system past the tipping point, are fundamental questions whose answer might change the way in which we address major societal challenges67, such as accelerating the post-carbon transition11 or contrasting vaccine-hesitancy68,69.

The model for tipping points dynamics in social convention introduced in this work extends the usual naming game framework towards more realism. First, we moved beyond peer-to-peer communication by considering group interactions not only restricted to pairs, as many actual interactions, both in real life and online, involve group discussions. In addition, we investigated the effects of imperfect social influence and considered real social structures for interactions. Our results show that critical mass dynamics can be initiated by minorities of very different sizes, including by an (almost) arbitrarily small minority, and that groups play a crucial role in determining the minority takeover. For example, one single individual with no special power or wealth can overturn the social conventions held by a group of hundreds of peers. Counter-intuitively, this happens when agents are not fully inclined to let go of the convention they currently use in favour of a new one. Note that, if agents are extremely reluctant to change, the system remains in a state where both norms co-exist at a similar level and many agents hold both norms. To consider realistic interactions, we have performed extensive numerical simulations on higher-order social networks constructed from empirical data and including group interactions of very different sizes, confirming that the findings hold in a broad region of the parameter space and for different interaction settings. Moreover, we have unveiled an interesting role of the size of interacting groups. Recently, large groups have been found to have a dominant role in seeding and sustaining contagion processes on hypergraphs70. Here, we have shown a non-monotonic behaviour in which both small and large group interactions favour the committed minority. We believe that our group communication model, which includes higher-order effects in micro-interactions, opens up a new direction in naming game applications to study opinion spreading and norm emergence. For instance, it would be relevant to explore how the influence of a minority can be maximised70,71,72, depending on whether its members tend to be cohesive or part of different groups. More broadly, this confirms the relevance of going beyond network representations and taking into account higher-order interactions when modelling social phenomena36,41.

It is important to delimit the scope of our findings. The major limitation of our results is, of course, that they have been obtained in the context of a single theoretical model, i.e., the naming game framework. However, this model has been previously used in several theoretical and empirical studies on tipping point dynamics in social convention, successfully reproducing the results obtained in controlled experiments7. As such, by generalising this model towards the inclusion of realistic interactions, by confirming how committed minorities of varying sizes can take over and even small committed minorities can be dramatically effective, and by shedding light on the effect of higher-order interactions, our work contributes to the development of more realistic modelling approaches and to the understanding of the critical mass phenomena. Naturally, it would be interesting to expand the results to other modelling frameworks of emergence or social cooperation42,73,74. An even more substantial step further would involve the design of novel controlled experiments7,75,76 to empirically assess the impact of the (different) group interactions introduced and of the various model parameters. For instance, p can be tuned by giving specific instructions to some participants to act as committed, while the role of β could be mimicked by artificial agents similar to bots77,78 that could prevent convergence with a tunable probability.

A second limitation is that our model cannot fully account for the complexity of real world interactions. While this is certainly true, it is worth stressing that we have considered more realistic interactions patterns than ever before in this context, or for that matter in many multi-agent models. Future work may further enrich this aspect by considering the effect of community structures79 and of temporal (higher-order) networks24,48,80. Moreover, the model and the generalisations we have considered lend themselves easily to many natural extensions: in particular, the parameter β describing the modulation of social influence could depend on agents’ properties, such as their centrality, or on the size of each interacting group. The activity of a group (probability to be selected at each time step) could also depend on its size. Co-evolution of the interaction structure and of the norms could also be introduced in the model81. Finally, it would be very interesting to investigate the behaviour of our model when agents committed to different opinions are present82, with two distinct minorities pushing each a distinct new norm against an initial well established one.

Methods

Data description and aggregation

We build empirical hypergraphs by aggregating six different data sets of temporally resolved interactions. Four of these data sets, provided by the SocioPatterns collaboration83, describe face-to-face interactions collected in different social contexts: a workplace (InVS15)84, a primary school (LyonSchool)85, a conference (SFHH)86, and a high school (Thiers13)58. Data from these experiments are initially aggregated by using a temporal window of 15 min and the maximal cliques within each temporal snapshot are retained (a similar procedure was used in Ref. 49). We then simply filtered the cliques by removing those that appeared only once, and finally used them to build each of the four empirical hypergraphs considered. The other two data sets involve considerably bigger interactions, and it is evident from the group size distributions reported in Fig. 3. The Email-EU dataset refers to email communications from a European research institution87, where each node represent a different email address and each hyperlink involves the sender and the (multiple) recipients of each message (1-second resolution). Finally, the Congress-bills data set refers to legislative bills in the U.S. congress88, where each node represent a person in the congress and hyperlinks join sponsors and co-sponsors of bills put forward in the House of Representatives and the Senate. No additional data processing has been performed on these last two data sets, as they already come in the form of simplices from Ref. 33.

The six empirical hypergraphs, in addition to describing very different types of interactions and contexts, are composed by different numbers of nodes N and groups E: N = 217, E = 3704 (InVS15), N = 242, E = 8010 (LyonSchool), N = 403, E = 7741 (SFHH), N = 327, E = 4862 (Thiers13), N = 9,79, E = 209,005 (Email-EU), N = 1718, E = 105,929 (Congress-bills). The histograms of group sizes are shown in Fig. 3 and in Supplementary Fig. 3, while generalised degree distributions are reported in Supplementary Fig. 6.

Stochastic simulations

We run agent-based stochastic simulations of the generalised NG model on real-world social structures and on idealised homogeneous populations of N = 1000 agents. In this latter case, simulations are performed assuming an homogeneous mixing population: all agents can potentially interact with each other. In both cases the dynamics evolves in the following way. At each timestep a group is chosen at random, either from the actual list of groups composing the empirical dataset, or in the homogeneous case, by selecting at random k nodes. One of the nodes composing the selected group, randomly chosen, acts as a speaker and the remaining nodes as hearers. The status of each node is then updated according to the specific rules defined in the model. The process is repeated until the system reaches an absorbing state (with all the nodes holding the same norm) or a steady state for the densities of agents holding a given norm. Densities in the steady state are computed by taking the average over 100 values sampled from the last 50,000 steps. The results shown in the figures correspond to median and standard deviations computed on 50 runs with random initial conditions (i.e., with a random selection of committed agents).